Summary

Education, Participation, and the Revival of U.S. Economic Growth
Author(s):
Dale Jorgenson, Harvard University
Mun Ho, Resources for the Future
Jon Samuels, Bureau of Economic Analysis
Downloads:
The Outlook for Labor Quality Growth in the U.S.
Author(s):
Mary Daly, Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco
John Fernald, Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco
Bart Hobijn, Arizona State University
Accounting for the Rise in College Tuition
Author(s):
Grey Gordon, Indiana University
Summary:

Gordon and Hedlund develop a quantitative model of higher education to test explanations for the steep rise in college tuition between 1987 and 2010. The framework extends the quality-maximizing college paradigm of Epple, Romano, Sarpca, and Sieg (2013) and embeds it in an incomplete markets, life-cycle environment. The researchers measure how much changes in underlying costs, reforms to the Federal Student Loan Program (FSLP), and changes in the college earnings premium have caused tuition to increase. All these changes combined generate a 106% rise in net tuition between 1987 and 2010, which more than accounts for the 78% increase seen in the data. Changes in the FSLP alone generate a 102% tuition increase, and changes in the college premium generate a 24% increase. The researchers' findings cast doubt on Baumol's cost disease as a driver of higher tuition.

Downloads:
The Outlook for U.S. Labor Quality Growth
Author(s):
Canyon L. Bosler, Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco
Mary Daly, Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco
John Fernald, Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco
Bart Hobijn, Arizona State University
Summary:

Between 1950 and 2007, labor quality growth in the U.S. contributed about 0.4 percentage point per year to growth in GDP per hour. This growth was mainly driven by increases in educational attainment and labor market experience associated with population aging. Looking ahead, the leveling off of educational attainment and the retirement of older workers will be drags on labor quality growth. How much of a drag depends on how much of the cyclical adjustment in the composition of employment towards higher skilled workers that occurred during the Great Recession will persist. Taking all of these factors into account, Bosler, Daly, Fernald, and Hobijn forecast that labor quality growth will decline by about 0.25 percentage points a year over the next 10 years compared to the past 15 years. Should employment composition return to its pre-recession levels, the full effects of slower educational attainment growth and Baby Boom retirements would be felt, resulting in labor quality growth well below the researchers' baseline.

Downloads:
The Requirements of Jobs: Evidence from a Nationally Representative Survey
Author(s):
Maury Gittleman, Bureau of Labor Statistics
Kristen A. Monaco, Bureau of Labor Statistics
Nicole Nestoriak, Bureau of Labor Statistics
Downloads:
Underemployment in the Early Careers of College Graduates Following the Great Recession
Author(s):
Jaison R. Abel, Federal Reserve Bank of New York
Summary:

Though labor market conditions steadily improved following the Great Recession, underemployment among recent college graduates continued to climb, reaching highs not seen since the early 1990s. In this paper, Abel and Deitz take a closer look at the jobs held by underemployed college graduates in the early stages of their careers during this period. The researchers show that relatively few recent graduates were working in low-skilled service jobs, and that many of the underemployed worked in fairly well paid non-college jobs requiring some degree of knowledge and skill. The authors also find that the likelihood of being underemployed was lower for those with technically oriented and occupation-specific majors than it was for those with degrees in more general fields. Moreover, their analysis suggests that underemployment is a temporary phase for many recent college graduates as they transition to better jobs after spending some time in the labor market, particularly for those who start their careers in low-skilled service jobs.

Downloads:
High-Skilled Immigration and the Rise of STEM Occupations in US Employment
Author(s):
Gordon H. Hanson, Harvard University and NBER
Matthew J. Slaughter, Dartmouth College and NBER
Summary:

In this paper, Hanson and Slaughter document the importance of high-skilled immigration for U.S. employment in STEM fields. To begin, they review patterns of U.S. employment in STEM occupations among workers with at least a college degree. These patterns mirror the cycle of boom and bust in the U.S. technology industry. Among younger workers, the share of hours worked in STEM jobs peaked around the year 2000, at the height of the dot-com bubble. STEM employment shares are just now approaching these previous highs. Next, the researchers consider the importance of immigrant labor to STEM employment. Immigrants account for a disproportionate share of jobs in STEM occupations, in particular among younger workers and among workers with a master's degree or PhD. Foreign-born presence is most pronounced in computer-related occupations, such as software programming. The majority of foreign-born workers in STEM jobs arrived in the U.S. at age 21 or older. Although the authors do not know the visa history of these individuals, their age at arrival is consistent with the H-1B visa being an important mode of entry for highly trained STEM workers into the U.S. Finally, the researchers examine wage differences between native and foreign-born labor. Whereas foreign-born workers earn substantially less than native-born workers in non-STEM occupations, the native-foreign born earnings difference in STEM jobs is economically much less significant. Further, foreign-born workers in STEM fields reach earnings parity with native workers much more quickly than they do in non-STEM fields. Whereas in non-STEM jobs, foreign-born workers require 20 years or more in the U.S. to reach earnings parity with natives, in STEM fields they achieve parity in less than a decade.

Downloads:
Skills, Education, and U.S. Economic Growth:
Are U.S. Workers Being Adequately Prepared for the 21st Century World of Work?
Author(s):
Charles R. Hulten, University of Maryland and NBER
Valerie A. Ramey, University of California, San Diego and NBER
Summary:

This paper studies trends in the demand for and supply of skills and the implications for future U.S. economic growth. Hulten and Ramey begin by noting that new technology not only increases the demand for higher order skills, it also depends on them to create and diffuse the technology. A work force that cannot play this role may limit the rate of innovation and affect the growth in living standards. Analyzing the demand for skills, the researchers link the growth in demand for non‐routine cognitive and non‐cognitive skills to the rapid growth in intangible capital. When intangible capital is added to a modified version of the BLS sources‐of‐growth model, it is found to be the largest systematic source of growth, explaining more than a quarter of the growth of output per worker hour from 1995 to 2007. The recognition of intangibles thus accords a significantly greater role for skills and education in the process of growth than the BLS approach. The researchers then review the evidence on trends in the supply of skills and conclude that supply of certain skills is not growing as fast as demand for those skills. This mismatch can explain some of the rise in wage inequality and has negative implications for the future of U.S. growth.

Downloads:
The Requirements of Jobs: Evidence from a Nationally Representative Survey
Author(s):
Maury Gittleman, Bureau of Labor Statistics
Kristen A. Monaco, Bureau of Labor Statistics
Nicole Nestoriak, Bureau of Labor Statistics

In addition to the conference paper, the research was distributed as NBER Working Paper w22218, which may be a more recent version.

School Spending and Student Performance in OECD Countries, 1998-2011
Author(s):
Edward N. Wolff, New York University and NBER
Summary:

Using data on school spending for 31 OECD countries over years 1988 to 2011 by level and type of expenditure, Wolff first presents a new formulation of the cost disease model and derives a new implicit price deflator for educational expenditures. The cost disease effect in overall education spending is estimated to be about one percentage point per year relative to the GDP deflator. Second, unlike many previous studies, Wolff finds a positive and significant effect of secondary school spending on both PISA math and literacy scores (both significant at the one percent level). Primary school spending is also a significant factor in explaining PISA literacy scores. The econometric results are slightly weaker on the basis of the new educational deflator.

Downloads:
Recent Flattening in the Higher Education Wage Premium: Polarization, Deskilling, or Both?
Author(s):
Robert G. Valletta, Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco
Summary:

The wage premium for individuals with a college or graduate degree rose substantially in the 1980s and 1990s but has changed little since the year 2000. Valletta assesses this flattening in the higher education wage premium with reference to two leading explanations of employment patterns in recent decades: the "polarization" hypothesis (Autor 2014) and the "deskilling" hypothesis (Beaudry, Green, and Sand 2013). The results suggest that ongoing polarization in employment patterns has not bolstered the relative wages of highly educated workers in occupations that require extensive skills. The flattening of returns to higher education appears to be driven by direct competition across higher education groups for similar jobs, broadly consistent with deskilling.

Downloads:
Non-Cognitive Skills as Human Capital
Author(s):
Shelly Lundberg, University of California at Santa Barbara
Summary:

In recent years, a large number of studies have shown strong positive associations between so-called "non-cognitive skills" — a broad and ill-defined category of metrics encompassing personality, socio-emotional skills, and behaviors — and economic success and wellbeing. These skills appear to be malleable early in life, raising the possibility of interventions that can decrease inequality and enhance economic productivity. In this paper, Lundberg discusses the extensive practical and conceptual barriers to using non-cognitive skill measures in studies of economic growth, as well as to developing or evaluating relevant policies. The researcher demonstrates several of these problems through a set of empirical analyses based on the non-cognitive measures available in NLSY97 and AddHealth data. There is a lack of general agreement on what non-cognitive skills are and how to measure them across developmental stages, and the reliance on behavioral measures of skills ensures that both skill indicators themselves, and their payoffs, will be context-dependent. The empirical examples show that indicators of adolescent skills have strong associations with educational attainment, but not subsequent labor market outcomes, and illustrate some problems in interpreting apparent skill gaps across demographic groups.

Downloads:
Wage Inequality and Cognitive Skills: Re-Opening the Debate
Author(s):
Summary:

Inequality in the United States is high by international standards, and keeps rising. This is likely to bring significant social as well as economic costs, including lower growth. In this paper, Broecke, Quintini, and Vandeweyer use the Survey of Adult Skills (PIAAC) to revisit the debate on the relative importance of skills in explaining international differences in wage inequality. While simple decomposition exercises suggest that skills only play a very minor role, demand and supply analysis indicates that the relative net supply of skills could explain 29% of the higher top-end wage inequality in the United States. The authors' analysis also suggests that skills could explain a substantial portion of the racial wage gap, as well as between individuals from different socio-economic backgrounds. Finally, the researchers find little support for the argument that higher wage inequality in the United States may be compensated for by better relative employment outcomes of the low-skilled.

Downloads:

In addition to the conference paper, the research was distributed as NBER Working Paper w21965, which may be a more recent version.

Participants

Below is a list of conference attendees.
Ozlen Luznar, Social Security Administration
Nabeel Alsalam, Congressional Budget Office
Roger Betancourt, University of Maryland
William Carrington, Congressional Budget Office
Baoline Chen, Bureau of Economic Analysis
Deniz Civril, Wellesley College
Gail Cohen, The National Academies of Sciences
Lucy Eldridge, Bureau of Labor Statistics
Ekkehard Ernst, ILO International Institute for Labour Studies
Abdul Erumban, The Conference Board
Nancy Gordon, U.S. Census Bureau
Justin Harper, Bureau of Economic Analysis
Denis Healy, National Bureau of Economic Research
Arnold Katz, Bureau of Economic Analysis, retired
Gad Levanon, The Conference Board
Brett Maranjian, NBER
Stephen Merrill, Duke University
Joshua K. Montes, Federal Reserve Board
Daniel Newlon, American Economic Association
Sabrina Pabilonia, Bureau of Labor Statistics
John Seliski, Congressional Budget Office
William Wiatrowski, Bureau of Labor Statistics
Erin L. Wolcott, Middlebury College
Joyce Zickler, Federal Reserve Board (retired)

More from NBER

In addition to working papers, the NBER disseminates affiliates’ latest findings through a range of free periodicals — the NBER Reporter, the NBER Digest, the Bulletin on Retirement and Disability, and the Bulletin on Health — as well as online conference reports, video lectures, and interviews.

Economics of Digitization Figure 1
  • Article
The NBER Economics of Digitization Project, established in 2010 with support from the Alfred P. Sloan Foundation,...
claudiagoldinpromoimagelecture.png
  • Lecture
Claudia Goldin, the Henry Lee Professor of Economics at Harvard University and a past president of the American...
2020 Methods Lecture Promo Image
  • Lecture
The extent to which individual responses to household surveys are protected from discovery by outside parties depends...